- 1 Simulation rules
- 2 Socio-economic costs
- 3 Epi model
- 4 Econ model
- 5 Closure policies
- 6 Pathogen profiles
- 7 DAEDALUS model parameters
- 8 Notation
This document describes the DAEDALUS model that is used in the CEPI application. The DAEDALUS model simulates a single epidemic in a single country. Details of how the DAEDALUS model is used as a part of the methodology of the CEPI application is presented in a separate report, which also details the scenarios which are expressed as vaccination rates and are inputs to the DAEDALUS model.
- The country is instantiated with two random variables: the response time, and the pathogen importation time
- The response time is the day at which the country reports having seen X hospital cases, where X is a random number between 1 and 20
- The importation time is a random number between 0 and 20 days. An importation time of 0 days would be equivalent to the spillover event.
- The epidemic simulation starts at the response or the importation time (the one that is smaller)
- At the importation time, five people are moved from compartment S to compartment E
- At the response time, testing begins and working from home begins
- If closure policies (RC1, RC2, or RC3) are being implemented, the rules in Tables 5.1 or 5.2 are followed
- Vaccination is a model input whose details depend on the scenario. The model allows for two vaccines to be administered flexibly, in that the first is not a prerequisite for the second. In the CEPI application, the first vaccine is a broadly protective sarbecovirus vaccine (BPSV) and the second is a strain-specific vaccine (SSV).
- Closures, working from home and testing end when vaccine rollout completes (or if other stopping criteria are met, see Tables 5.1 and 5.2)
- When vaccine rollout is complete, the doubling time is more than 30 days and there are fewer than 1,000 people in hospital, the simulation ends.
We assign monetary values to years of life lost (YLL) and to years of education in order to add health and education costs of sector-closure policies to the costs of economic closures. We define the total socio-economic loss (TSL) of an epidemic as the sum of the three types of loss:
where
We measure the cost of economic closures in terms of lost gross value
added (GVA): the GDP generated by an economic configuration is the
maximum GVA (denoted
for
All economic sectors contribute GVA according to the level they are open
for production, except for the education sector which contributes its
maximum possible GVA,
where
with
Then the total GDP is
and the GDP loss compared to the maximum is
To value lives lost, we make use of the expected remaining life years
per age group estimated by the Global Burden of Disease Network (Global
Burden of Disease Collaborative Network 2021). These are used to
estimate the expected number of years of life lost per death, and to
estimate the value of a life year. We map the remaining life expectancy
To estimate the expected number of life years lost per SARS-X death, we
take into account the probability to die given infection,
The total number of years lost given
The value of a statistical life (VSL) reflects individuals’ willingness to trade wealth for reductions in risk of mortality. We rely on the intrinsic rather than instrumental interpretation of the valuation of life (Cutler and Summers 2020), and we use an existing estimate of the VSL to estimate the value of a life year (VLY). We interpret the VSL as a population-weighted average (Ananthapavan et al. 2021; Robinson, Sullivan, and Shogren 2021), where each age group has a VSL defined by the number of expected life years remaining, and where each year has the same value:
Following The Global Fund (2022), “In this way, we made a choice to value deaths proportionally to the remaining life expectancy associated with the counterfactual of that death (how long they would live if they had not died)”.
We estimate a country’s VSL using the VSL of the USA, adjusting for the difference in income. We also adjust for the elasticity of willingness to pay for reductions in mortality risk relative to income. The income elasticity is likely larger in lower-income countries than in higher-income countries because the opportunity cost of spending on basic necessities becomes large if incomes are at or below subsistence levels (Hammitt 2020).
We estimate VSL as a function of GDP, relative to values for the USA:
Here,
Parameter
Parameter
Method | Probability |
|
|
|
|
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
OECD/IHME/World Bank | 0.5 | Sampled from WB data | Uniform(0.9, 1.2) | Uniform(0.9, 1.2) | Uniform(0.9, 1.2) | 0.8 |
Viscusi/Masterman | 0.5 | 1 | 1 | 1 | Uniform(0.85, 1) | Uniform(0.85, 1) |
Table 2.1: values for elasticities, adapted from Robinson, Sullivan, and Shogren (2021), Table 2 (page 25)
We note that in the methods presented in Table 2.1 there is a relationship between exchange rate and elasticity, in that the flatter elasticities of Viscusi/Masterman are matched with GDP based on MER, whereas the more graduated elasticities of the OECD/IHME/World Bank method are matched with GDP based on PPP. This might be because these choices enact inverse transformations of low VSL values for GDP (Figure 2.1).

Figure 2.1: Exposition of different methods to estimate VSL from GDP per capita relative to the USA. On the y axis is VSL expressed as a percentage of GDP per capita. The grey line indicates the VSL of the USA. We compare GDP per capita expressed using market exchange rates (MER) vs. purchasing power parity (PPP), and an income elasticity of 1 vs. 1.5. Data source: World Bank.
The loss due to school closure is
where
For the value of a year of education, we use the method of (Psacharopoulos et al. 2021).
for discount rate
The value
The epidemiological component of the DAEDALUS model is a deterministic compartmental model that consists of seven disease states (susceptible, exposed, asymptomatic infectious, symptomatic infectious, hospitalised, recovered, and deceased), in triplicate to represent vaccination states unvaccinated, vaccinated with the BPSV, and vaccinated with the SSV. The population is stratified by age (into four age groups: pre-school children, school-age children, working-age adults, and retirement-age adults). The working-age adults are further stratified into 46 groups: 45 economic sectors, plus one non-working group.

Figure 3.1: Disease state
transitions.
Possible transitions between disease states are shown in Figure
3.1. Transition rates are functions
of time
The rate of infection of susceptible individuals,
with
Here,
is the rate to asymptomatic infectiousness, where
is the rate of recovery from asymptomatic infection;
is the rate of symptom onset;
is the rate of recovery from symptomatic infection, where
is the baseline probability to be hospitalised (
is the rate of hospitalisation following symptomatic infection.
is the rate of recovery of hospitalised patients, where
is the expected time to be in compartment
is the rate of death following hospitalisation.
In our model,

Figure 3.2: Vaccine state
transitions.
Quantity | BPSV | SSV |
---|---|---|
Time to develop immunity | 21 days | 21 days |
Effectiveness against infection | 0.35 | 0.55 |
Effectiveness against hospitalisation | 0.8 | 0.9 |
Effect on transmission | 0 | 0 |
Rate of waning | 0 | 0 |
Table 3.1: Vaccine effects. The Time to develop immunity is the average time it takes a person to go from the Susceptible compartment to the Vaccinated equivalent compartment, such that the rate of transition is 1/21 per day. The Effectiveness against infection is one minus the relative risk of infection of a vaccinated person compared to an unvaccinated person. The Effectiveness against hospitalisation is one minus the relative risk of hospitalisation of a vaccinated person compared to an unvaccinated person. The Effect on transmission is one minus the relative infectiousness of an infectious vaccinated person compared to an infectious unvaccinated person. The Rate of waning is the rate at which the vaccine effects decay over time.
The configuration
- Worker absence due to sector closure
- Worker absence due to working from home
- Student absence due to school closure
- Customer absence due to sector closure: impact on workers
- Customer absence due to sector closure: impact on customers
We approach this differently from (Haw et al. 2022). Instead of contact matrices from (Prem et al. 2021), we use those from (Walker et al. 2020). Instead of work contacts from (Béraud et al. 2015), we use those from (Jarvis et al. 2023). (Haw et al. 2022) modelled closures using a combination of moving workers between sector compartments and a non-working compartment, and scaling of contacts. Here, we only use contacts to model closures, and do not move workers out of their compartments. An advantage of this is that workers within sectors retain their infection histories.
We construct contact matrix
Matrix
and
We get to the matrix
for
In setting up a country, we sample values for
Community-to-worker contacts (matrix
With
Values for
Finally,
![Fraction of contacts made at work, from [@Jarvis2023]. Extrapolated from three countries (UK, Belgium, Netherlands), whose values are all close to 40%, using time-use survey results for fraction of time spent at work (OECD, last updated December 2023, 33 countries, with values ranging from 12 to 25% (and the three reference countries have values 16 to 18%)).](/robj411/p2_drivers/raw/main/README_files/figure-gfm/workfrac.png)
Figure 3.3: Fraction of contacts made at work, from (Jarvis et al. 2023). Extrapolated from three countries (UK, Belgium, Netherlands), whose values are all close to 40%, using time-use survey results for fraction of time spent at work (OECD, last updated December 2023, 33 countries, with values ranging from 12 to 25% (and the three reference countries have values 16 to 18%)).
![Number of contacts made at work, from [@Jarvis2023]. Diamonds show average numbers and ranges are 50% quantile intervals. We sample values from half to double the average. Data come from UK, Netherlands and Switzerland, with occupation ISCO-88 mapped to ISCO-08 then SOC-10 then ISIC rev 4 using ONS data.](/robj411/p2_drivers/raw/main/README_files/figure-gfm/allsector45.png)
Figure 3.4: Number of contacts made at work, from (Jarvis et al. 2023). Diamonds show average numbers and ranges are 50% quantile intervals. We sample values from half to double the average. Data come from UK, Netherlands and Switzerland, with occupation ISCO-88 mapped to ISCO-08 then SOC-10 then ISIC rev 4 using ONS data.
![Fraction of non-school and non-work contacts made in hospitality settings, by age group, from [@Jarvis2023].](/robj411/p2_drivers/raw/main/README_files/figure-gfm/hospfrac.png)
Figure 3.8: Fraction of non-school and non-work contacts made in hospitality settings, by age group, from (Jarvis et al. 2023).
![Distribution of non-school and non-work contacts made in hospitality settings by age group, from [@Jarvis2023].](/robj411/p2_drivers/raw/main/README_files/figure-gfm/conagefrac.png)
Figure 3.9: Distribution of non-school and non-work contacts made in hospitality settings by age group, from (Jarvis et al. 2023).
We construct
School contacts under
Matrix
The value
where we sum over only the hospitality sectors.
for
Here, there is superlinear scaling of
We parametrise the effects of ‘uncosted transmission reductions’ (UTR) in the model using Google’s mobility data (Figure 3.10). These changes in mobility were consequences of both government mandates and individual’s choices. As we cannot separate the two, we consider a range of possibilities, based on the range of mobility changes observed for a given level of stringency (Figure 3.11). In our model, the mandated economic configuration leads to a change in contacts. We associate the reduction in contacts, which translates as a relative reduction in transmission, with the reduction in mobility.

Figure 3.10: Mobility trajectories in 2020 for all countries, with points showing the point at which the largest drop was observed. Trajectories are averaged over “Retail and recreation”, “Transit stations” and “Workplaces” and smoothed with a spline of 80 knots.
- We want to write mobility as a function of mandate and some epi
outcome, e.g. deaths:
$\rho(t) = (1-p^8)f(d(t),e(t)) + p^8$ where$\rho(t)$ is mobility,$d$ is deaths per million,$e$ is government mandate, and$0 < p^8 < 1$ is the baseline. - We want mobility to drop monotonically with both the mandate and the
epi outcome:
$\frac{\partial f}{\partial d}<0$ ,$\frac{\partial f}{\partial e}<0$ . - We want a maximum mobility of 1 when both the mandate and the epi
outcome are 0:
$f(0,0)=1$ . - We want mobility to approach
$p^8$ when the mandate and the epi outcome become large:$\lim_{d\to 10^6, e\to 1}f(d,e)= 0$ . - We want to allow for the possibility of redundancy between the two
variables:
$f(0,0)/f(0,e) > f(d,0)/f(d,e)$ and$f(0,0)/f(d,0) > f(0,e)/f(d,e)$ for$d,e>0$ .
A simple model to achieve these criteria is:
The implications of this modelling choice are that two extremes are possible in terms of behaviour under (unseen) circumstances of a severe moment in an outbreak: 1, it is possible that social distancing comes “free” (i.e. that you get the same reduction in transmission with and without closures and, without closures, there is no economic cost); and 2, there is no voluntary social distancing, and behaviour is independent of epidemiological circumstances. This is an assumption commonly made to create the counterfactual in evaluating impacts of vaccine programmes. This is a very large source of uncertainty, and we expect it to be identified as such in value-of-information analyses.
Finally, we assume that the effect wanes over time, with the minimum (baseline) tending to 1 with a rate of 0 to 0.1% per day.
We assume that infectious people who know their status have a compliance
The economic model is measuring GDP by summing GVA over sectors and over time taking into account the extent to which sectors are open, as described in Section 2.1.
The economy is stratified by sector following the International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities (ISIC) Rev. 4 as used by the OECD (UN Economic and Social Affairs 2008). Economic output is measured as the sum of gross value added (GVA) of all sectors over the epidemic period, expressed as a percentage of pre-epidemic GVA summed over the same period.
Openness comes primarily from the economic configuration which is a policy choice, mandated in response to the epidemic (see Section 5). There are potentially additional losses due to worker sickness and death (see Section 2.1) and due to lost tourism, which is an exogenous random variable (see Section 4.1). We do not model changes to supply or demand, reductions in consumption and labour supply due to infection avoidance of individuals, interruptions in supply chains, or changes in imports and exports.
Lost education is also quantified monetarily and constitutes an economic cost. Unlike the other losses, they are not contemporaneous with the epidemic, but losses that unfold into the future. The assumptions and equations are described in Section 2.3.
As there is no “tourism” sector in the 45-sector classification we are using, to model the impact of changes to tourism, we identify the “Food and accommodation services” sector with tourism. This is imperfect. The correlation of their % contributions to GDP is 0.64 and the order of magnitude is similar (1 to 7% vs 2 to 10% of GDP). The other two sectors considered (Air transport and Arts, entertainment and recreation) have little correlation with tourism in terms of % of GDP. (See Figure 4.1.)

Figure 4.1: Correlations between tourism-related data. First: UN Tourism (2023b). Second to fourth: UN Tourism (2023a). Fifth to seventh: OECD.
For many countries, tourism was reduced in the COVID-19 pandemic not because of domestic mandates but because of reduced international travel. Therefore, the fraction of tourism that comes from abroad is a factor that can determine the impact of a pandemic on a country’s GDP potentially independently of what happens within the country. (A useful model extension would be to include some dependence on country factors, e.g. case numbers.)
We model mitigation via business closures, which are mandated by sector.
We represent openness with values
where
Therefore, the contribution of the GVA of the food and accommodation services sector is limited either by the pandemic, or by the sector-closure policy - whichever is lower.
We model the distribution of

Figure 4.2: Distributions of tourism-related data from UN Tourism (2023a). In grey are the subset of countries for which we have GVA data by sector.
We model
We write
where
Here,
For each sector in each country, we have the 90% interval for the proportion of people who can work from home from Gottlieb et al. (2021). We assume that the value we sample within the range is related to internet infrastructure, so that a low value in one sector implies low values in all sectors. We:
- take the subset of countries in the income group (LLMIC / UMIC / HIC);
- take the minimum of the lower bounds by sector (5%);
- take the maximum of the upper bounds by sector (95%);
- sample from a uniform distribution between these bounds, taking the same quantile for each sector.
We assume that remote working happens to its fullest extent for the whole period of mitigation for all policies.
Impacts of mandated closures of businesses and schools on epidemics can be described using three factors: length, stringency, and frequency. We model mandated closures using a discrete set of predefined policies, which specify the stringency of closures in each sector. The policies we use are the same for each country. The length and frequency of economic closures are endogenous to the model (via its epidemiology), and therefore depend on the dynamics of the epidemic that is being modelled.
We define four generic policies that might be adopted once a novel pathogen has been identified. The policies represent possible choices that range from very stringent to laissez faire, and are grounded in real-life observations. We name the policies no closures (NC) and reactive closures 1 to 3 (RC1 to RC3), and they are depicted in Figure 5.1, structured by the qualities that distinguish them.
The three sector-closure policies are each defined by a pair of economic configurations, and rules for moving between them. An economic configuration is a vector specifying the extent to which each sector is open, expressed as a percentage. Our economic configurations are constructed using data from three countries (Indonesia (RC1), the United Kingdom (RC2), and Australia (RC3)), via the manifest economic impacts in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic. We take the sectoral GVA observed the COVID-19 pandemic expressed as a percentage of the values observed in the year before (OECD), i.e. we assume that the relative GVA reflects the degree to which sectors were open.
In reality, the observed effects combined mandated closures, reductions in consumption and labour supply due to infection avoidance of individuals, interruptions in supply chains, and changes in imports and exports. However, these effects have not been disentangled, and in DAEDALUS we model only the mandate. This is equivalent to saying that we assume the mandate alone determined economic outcomes and we simulate their repeated application. Thus we neglect two factors in our model: first, population behaviour, and second, international trade, and we ignore their impacts in the COVID-19 pandemic by subsuming all effects into the mandate. (e.g. a pandemic that does not originate in or impact greatly China might have a much smaller economic cost).
The economic configurations define the sector closures for both the economic model and the epidemiological model. Contacts associated with sectors – between and among workers and customers – are scaled down with closures. GVA per sector is scaled according to economic configurations in the economic model.
For their dynamic implementation in the model, the three closure policies follow the same general pattern: they are defined by two economic configurations, which we refer to as heavy and light (where the “heavy” configuration has higher stringency than the “light” configuration; the configurations are tabulated in Table 5.3). The light configuration is implemented at the response time. Thereafter, the level of closure for the three policies is mandated in response to the state of the epidemic, reverting between states as determined by the transmission dynamics. Tables 5.1 and 5.2 show the transitions and their conditions. RC1 and RC2 respond to hospital occupancy, allowing cases to rise and using closures to allow them to fall again. RC1 keeps schools closed throughout, whereas RC2 has schools open in the light configuration. RC3 aims to reduce cases and then to keep them low. All mitigation is suspended when the vaccine rollout has reached its target coverage (which is when 80% of the eligible population have been vaccinated).

Figure 5.1: The four sector-closure
policy options. No closures (NC) does not mandate any closures. The
other three policies all implement reactive closures (RC), either in
response to hospital occupancy (RC1 and RC2) or
The sector-closure policies are defined as follows:
- NC: No closures are mandated.
- RC1: Schools are mandated to close to 10% of pre-epidemic levels throughout, and other economic sectors close to the heavy-closure economic configuration when hospital occupancy reaches 95% of its capacity, and change to the light configuration once occupancy is less than 25% capacity.
- RC2: Sectors (including the education sector) toggle between heavy and light closures reactively, as in RC1, albeit with slightly different economic configurations.
- RC3: Heavy closures are chosen when
$R_t>1.2$ and light closures when$R_t<0.95$ . Closures are maintained until$R_t<1$ without closures, or vaccination targets are reached.
All policies assume there is testing (Section 3.6), working from home (Section 4.2), and uncosted transmission reductions from behavioural changes (Section 3.5), which impact epidemiological outcomes. They do not directly impact economic outcomes, but indirectly may reduce the need for closures because of reduced incidence.
From/to | No closures | Light closures | Heavy closures |
---|---|---|---|
No closures | t |
||
Light closures | (Growth rate < 0.025 OR Hospital occupancy < 25% capacity) AND vaccine rollout complete OR |
Hospital occupancy > 95% capacity | |
Heavy closures | Hospital occupancy < 25% capacity AND t > 7 + last change time |
Table 5.1: State transition rules for policies RC1 and RC2. See Table 5.3 for details of closures.
From/to | No closures | Light closures | Heavy closures |
---|---|---|---|
No closures | t |
||
Light closures | Vaccine rollout complete OR |
||
Heavy closures | Vaccine rollout complete OR |
|
Table 5.2: State transition rules for policy RC3. See Table 5.3 for details of closures.
Table 5.3: Economic configurations used to implement strategies. Values are the openness of the sector expressed as a percentage. RC3 values are taken from Australia. Lockdown and RC2 values are taken from the UK. RC1 values are taken from Indonesia.
RC1 |
RC2 |
RC3 |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Sector |
Heavy closures |
Light closures |
Heavy closures |
Light closures |
Heavy closures |
Light closures |
Agriculture, hunting, forestry |
100 |
100 |
86 |
88 |
86 |
100 |
Fishing and aquaculture |
100 |
100 |
86 |
88 |
86 |
100 |
Mining and quarrying, energy producing products |
67 |
79 |
90 |
91 |
90 |
100 |
Mining and quarrying, non-energy producing products |
100 |
100 |
90 |
91 |
90 |
100 |
Mining support service activities |
100 |
100 |
90 |
91 |
90 |
100 |
Food products, beverages and tobacco |
100 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Textiles, textile products, leather and footwear |
89 |
92 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
98 |
Wood and products of wood and cork |
100 |
95 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
98 |
Paper products and printing |
100 |
98 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
98 |
Coke and refined petroleum products |
87 |
88 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
88 |
Chemical and chemical products |
100 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
88 |
Pharmaceuticals, medicinal chemical and botanical products |
100 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
88 |
Rubber and plastics products |
87 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
88 |
Other non-metallic mineral products |
92 |
89 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
88 |
Basic metals |
100 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Fabricated metal products |
90 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Computer, electronic and optical equipment |
90 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Electrical equipment |
90 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Machinery and equipment, nec |
89 |
95 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers |
66 |
82 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Other transport equipment |
66 |
82 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
100 |
Manufacturing nec; repair and installation of machinery and equipment |
98 |
100 |
70 |
94 |
70 |
98 |
Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply |
94 |
94 |
89 |
100 |
89 |
97 |
Water supply; sewerage, waste management and remediation activities |
100 |
100 |
92 |
98 |
92 |
97 |
Construction |
95 |
95 |
56 |
92 |
56 |
94 |
Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles |
92 |
97 |
64 |
100 |
64 |
100 |
Land transport and transport via pipelines |
83 |
100 |
63 |
82 |
63 |
100 |
Water transport |
81 |
98 |
63 |
82 |
63 |
100 |
Air transport |
16 |
42 |
63 |
82 |
63 |
18 |
Warehousing and support activities for transportation |
64 |
91 |
63 |
82 |
63 |
91 |
Postal and courier activities |
64 |
91 |
63 |
82 |
63 |
91 |
Accommodation and food service activities |
77 |
91 |
10 |
85 |
10 |
92 |
Publishing, audiovisual and broadcasting activities |
100 |
100 |
88 |
91 |
88 |
100 |
Telecommunications |
100 |
100 |
88 |
91 |
88 |
100 |
IT and other information services |
100 |
100 |
88 |
91 |
88 |
100 |
Financial and insurance activities |
100 |
100 |
94 |
96 |
94 |
100 |
Real estate activities |
100 |
100 |
98 |
98 |
98 |
100 |
Professional, scientific and technical activities |
90 |
95 |
85 |
92 |
85 |
100 |
Administrative and support services |
90 |
95 |
66 |
80 |
66 |
90 |
Public administration and defence; compulsory social security |
96 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
100 |
Education |
10 |
10 |
10 |
100 |
10 |
100 |
Human health and social work activities |
100 |
100 |
75 |
92 |
75 |
100 |
Arts, entertainment and recreation |
90 |
96 |
55 |
71 |
55 |
94 |
Other service activities |
90 |
96 |
54 |
83 |
54 |
94 |
Activities of households as employers; undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of households for own use |
90 |
96 |
49 |
53 |
49 |
94 |
We sample pathogen profiles by defining distributions over the pathogen
parameters. The distributions are made using sourced data (Table
6.1), and are described in Table
6.2. Age profiles for severity
rates are shown in Figure 6.1. We sample
parameter values from distributions informed by the seven pathogen
profiles.
Table 6.1: Pathogen profiles. IHR: infection hospitalisation rate. IFR: infection fatality rate.
SARS-CoV-1 |
Influenza 2009 |
Influenza 1957 |
Influenza 1918 |
SARS-CoV-2 pre-alpha |
SARS-CoV-2 omicron |
SARS-CoV-2 delta |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
IHR in 0-4 age group |
0.058 |
0.0047 |
0.0009 |
0.12 |
0.000016 |
0.000033 |
0.00003 |
IHR in 5-9 age group |
0.058 |
0.0018 |
0.0009 |
0.021 |
0.000016 |
0.000033 |
0.00003 |
IHR in 10-14 age group |
0.058 |
0.0018 |
0.0009 |
0.026 |
0.00041 |
0.00059 |
0.00075 |
IHR in 15-19 age group |
0.058 |
0.0018 |
0.0009 |
0.053 |
0.00041 |
0.00059 |
0.00075 |
IHR in 20-24 age group |
0.082 |
0.0018 |
0.0009 |
0.091 |
0.01 |
0.0083 |
0.019 |
IHR in 25-29 age group |
0.082 |
0.0038 |
0.0009 |
0.16 |
0.01 |
0.0083 |
0.019 |
IHR in 30-34 age group |
0.082 |
0.0038 |
0.0009 |
0.13 |
0.034 |
0.02 |
0.063 |
IHR in 35-39 age group |
0.082 |
0.0038 |
0.0009 |
0.12 |
0.034 |
0.02 |
0.063 |
IHR in 40-44 age group |
0.3 |
0.0038 |
0.0009 |
0.088 |
0.042 |
0.016 |
0.079 |
IHR in 45-49 age group |
0.3 |
0.0038 |
0.023 |
0.064 |
0.042 |
0.016 |
0.079 |
IHR in 50-54 age group |
0.3 |
0.0071 |
0.023 |
0.088 |
0.082 |
0.021 |
0.15 |
IHR in 55-59 age group |
0.3 |
0.0071 |
0.023 |
0.063 |
0.082 |
0.021 |
0.15 |
IHR in 60-64 age group |
0.87 |
0.0071 |
0.023 |
0.16 |
0.12 |
0.031 |
0.22 |
IHR in 65-69 age group |
0.87 |
0.01 |
0.18 |
0.22 |
0.12 |
0.031 |
0.22 |
IHR in 70-74 age group |
0.87 |
0.01 |
0.18 |
0.26 |
0.17 |
0.061 |
0.31 |
IHR in 75-79 age group |
0.87 |
0.01 |
0.18 |
0.26 |
0.17 |
0.061 |
0.31 |
IHR in 80+ age group |
0.6 |
0.01 |
0.18 |
0.26 |
0.18 |
0.11 |
0.34 |
IFR in 0-4 age group |
0.015 |
0.00018 |
0.000067 |
0.015 |
0.000016 |
0.000033 |
0.00003 |
IFR in 5-9 age group |
0.015 |
0.000074 |
0.000067 |
0.0027 |
0.000016 |
0.000033 |
0.00003 |
IFR in 10-14 age group |
0.015 |
0.000074 |
0.000067 |
0.0032 |
0.00007 |
0.0001 |
0.00013 |
IFR in 15-19 age group |
0.015 |
0.00008 |
0.000067 |
0.0066 |
0.00007 |
0.0001 |
0.00013 |
IFR in 20-24 age group |
0.021 |
0.00008 |
0.000067 |
0.011 |
0.00031 |
0.00025 |
0.00057 |
IFR in 25-29 age group |
0.021 |
0.0002 |
0.000067 |
0.02 |
0.00031 |
0.00025 |
0.00057 |
IFR in 30-34 age group |
0.021 |
0.0002 |
0.000067 |
0.017 |
0.00084 |
0.00048 |
0.0016 |
IFR in 35-39 age group |
0.021 |
0.0002 |
0.000067 |
0.015 |
0.00084 |
0.00048 |
0.0016 |
IFR in 40-44 age group |
0.077 |
0.0002 |
0.000067 |
0.011 |
0.0016 |
0.0006 |
0.003 |
IFR in 45-49 age group |
0.077 |
0.00043 |
0.0017 |
0.008 |
0.0016 |
0.0006 |
0.003 |
IFR in 50-54 age group |
0.077 |
0.00043 |
0.0017 |
0.011 |
0.006 |
0.0015 |
0.011 |
IFR in 55-59 age group |
0.077 |
0.00043 |
0.0017 |
0.0078 |
0.006 |
0.0015 |
0.011 |
IFR in 60-64 age group |
0.22 |
0.00043 |
0.0017 |
0.021 |
0.019 |
0.005 |
0.036 |
IFR in 65-69 age group |
0.22 |
0.0066 |
0.013 |
0.028 |
0.019 |
0.005 |
0.036 |
IFR in 70-74 age group |
0.22 |
0.0066 |
0.013 |
0.033 |
0.043 |
0.016 |
0.079 |
IFR in 75-79 age group |
0.22 |
0.0066 |
0.013 |
0.033 |
0.043 |
0.016 |
0.079 |
IFR in 80+ age group |
0.15 |
0.0066 |
0.013 |
0.033 |
0.078 |
0.048 |
0.14 |
probability symptomatic |
0.87 |
0.67 |
0.67 |
0.67 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
latent period |
4.6 |
1.1 |
1.1 |
1.1 |
4.6 |
4 |
4 |
duration asymptomatic |
2.1 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
2.1 |
2.1 |
2.1 |
duration infectious and symptomatic given recovery without hospitalisation |
4 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
duration infectious and symptomatic given hospitalisation |
3.8 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
duration hospitalised given recovery |
23 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
12 |
5.5 |
7.6 |
duration hospitalised given death |
20 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
12 |
5.5 |
7.6 |
duration of infection-acquired immunity |
360 |
360 |
360 |
360 |
360 |
360 |
360 |
relative infectiousness of asymptomatic |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
basic reproduction number |
1.8 |
1.6 |
1.8 |
2.5 |
2.9 |
5.9 |
5.1 |
Model parameter name | Distribution | Distribution parameter values | Correlations |
---|---|---|---|
Probability symptomatic | Beta | 14.68, 7.30 | None |
Latent period | Gamma | 2.28, 1.06 | None |
Asymptomatic infectious period | Gamma | 139.0, 0.017 | None |
Time from symptom onset to recovery | Gamma | 18.61, 0.17 | 0.99 (time to hospitalisation); 0.60 ( |
Time from symptom onset to hospitalisation | Gamma | 21.21, 0.14 | 0.99 (time to recovery); 0.66 ( |
Time from hospitalisation to recovery | Gamma | 2.46, 3.75 | 0.997 |
Time from hospitalisation to death | Gamma | 2.93, 2.96 | 0.997 |
Time to immunity waning | Constant | Inf | None |
Relative infectiousness of asymptomatic | Constant | 0.58 | None |
Truncated normal | 2.45, 1.32; (1.5, 4) | 0.60 (time to recovery); 0.66 (time to hospitalisation) |
Table 6.2: Distributions for pathogen parameters used to sample synthetic pathogens. Distributions are built from values in Table 6.1.
Figure 6.1: Infection hospitalisation and fatality ratios are generated by modelling profiles from SARS and influenza ratios. x axis: age group index. y axis: log ratio. Colours: seven example profiles. Grey: sampled profiles. Profiles are built from values in Table 6.1.In this section we list the parameters used to construct a country in order to run the model. We organise them by the way in which they are sampled. Fixed values are described elsewhere in the documentation.
The following quantities are sampled from the set of values belonging to countries from one income level and/or uniform distributions:
- Population distribution by age
- Life expectancy
- Number of workers per sector
- GVA per worker per sector
- Community contact matrix
- Testing rate
- Scaling factors for all workplace-related contacts
- The extent to which there is uncosted transmission reduction
- Type of VSL calculation
- VSL elasticity
- Remote teaching effectiveness
- Date of importation
- Response time
- Size of epidemic seed
Table 7.1: Mean ages for all countries within each income-level group.
Income group |
Mean |
Min |
Max |
---|---|---|---|
LLMIC |
26.1 |
20.4 |
41.5 |
UMIC |
33.8 |
24 |
43.9 |
HIC |
40.1 |
29.8 |
50.7 |
Table 7.2: Mean life expectancy for all countries within each income-level group. Life expectancy as given “Expected years of life remaining” for the youngest age group (0 to 4 years old).
Income group |
Mean |
Min |
Max |
---|---|---|---|
LLMIC |
68.4 |
53.6 |
77.7 |
UMIC |
74.1 |
63.3 |
80.5 |
HIC |
79.2 |
73 |
83.4 |
The following are sampled from parametric distributions:
Table 7.3: Parameter distributions. Tourism parameters are those described in Section 4.1.4. “school1 fraction” and “school2 fraction” are the fractions of contacts that pre-school children and school-age children make in nursery and school, respectively. Work fraction is the fraction of contacts people in the working-age age group make in the workplace. hospitality1 fraction, hospitality2 fraction, hospitality3 fraction and hospitality4 fraction are the fractions of non-work, non-school contacts made in the hospitality setting for the four ordered age groups. hospitality age1, hospitality age2, hospitality age3 and hospitality age4 give the fractions of hospitality contacts made with age groups 20–64 and 65 and over, for the four age groups in order. Workforce in place is the fraction of 20 to 64 year olds counted among sector workers. (Workforce in place + unemployed = Workforce.) Hospital capacity is beds per 100,000 population.
Parameter |
Income group |
Distribution |
Parameter 1 |
Parameter 2 |
---|---|---|---|---|
internet coverage |
LLMIC |
Beta |
1.78 |
3.11 |
internet coverage |
UMIC |
Beta |
14.32 |
6.44 |
internet coverage |
HIC |
Beta |
9.57 |
1.39 |
remaining international tourism |
all |
Log normal |
-1.39 |
0.39 |
Labour share of GVA |
LLMIC |
Beta |
5.09 |
4.51 |
Labour share of GVA |
UMIC |
Beta |
7.06 |
8.18 |
Labour share of GVA |
HIC |
Beta |
7.97 |
6.87 |
gdp to gnippp |
LLMIC |
Gamma |
9.40 |
0.33 |
gdp to gnippp |
UMIC |
Gamma |
16.40 |
0.14 |
gdp to gnippp |
HIC |
Gamma |
11.89 |
0.12 |
Hospital capacity |
LLMIC |
Gamma |
1.30 |
20.20 |
Hospital capacity |
UMIC |
Gamma |
1.73 |
40.73 |
Hospital capacity |
HIC |
Gamma |
2.05 |
46.57 |
tourism parameter sum |
all |
NA |
6.73 |
NA |
Tourism to international |
all |
NA |
4.14 |
0.05 |
pupil teacher ratio |
LLMIC |
Gamma |
9.15 |
3.11 |
pupil teacher ratio |
UMIC |
Gamma |
13.29 |
1.22 |
pupil teacher ratio |
HIC |
Gamma |
14.53 |
0.86 |
school1 fraction |
all |
Beta |
2.14 |
3.38 |
school2 fraction |
all |
Beta |
13.23 |
10.85 |
work fraction |
all |
Beta |
10.94 |
13.83 |
hospitality1 fraction |
all |
Beta |
21.08 |
381.22 |
hospitality2 fraction |
all |
Beta |
3.71 |
88.67 |
hospitality3 fraction |
all |
Beta |
19.44 |
149.44 |
hospitality4 fraction |
all |
Beta |
7.69 |
62.33 |
hospitality age1 |
all |
NA |
0.63 |
0.09 |
hospitality age2 |
all |
NA |
0.57 |
0.06 |
hospitality age3 |
all |
NA |
0.85 |
0.08 |
hospitality age4 |
all |
NA |
0.56 |
0.41 |
workforce in place |
LLMIC |
Beta |
3.69 |
2.16 |
workforce in place |
UMIC |
Beta |
5.72 |
2.64 |
workforce in place |
HIC |
Beta |
9.26 |
2.01 |
We model these values with gamma distributions. For LLMICs, we have parameters 1.3 and 0.05. For UMICs, we have parameters 1.73 and 0.02. For HICs, we have parameters 2.05 and 0.02. (Data sources: World Bank (beds); OECD, WHO euro (bed occupancy rates).)
We estimate the average annual income per working-age adult as the total GVA multiplied by the fraction of GVA that goes to labour divided by the number of working-age adults. For the fraction of GVA that goes to labour we use PWT estimates from 2011 (Figure 7.2).
We model these values with Beta distributions. For LLMICs, we have parameters 5.09 and 4.51. For UMICs, we have parameters 7.06 and 8.18. For HICs, we have parameters 7.97 and 6.87.

Figure 7.3: Vaccines administered per day, on average, in each country as a percent of population. Data source: fully vaccinated people from OWID (2022).
Figure 7.3 shows histograms of COVID-19 vaccine administration rates by income level. Values are estimates of administration rates of complete schedules given. Administration rates are estimated as the best-fit slope observed in the pandemic period (Figure 7.4). The administration slope ideally represents the highest rate possible: rates are often low to begin with, due to limited supply. They are often low at the end, due to depleted demand.
Using the method illustrated in Figure 7.4, we estimate how many countries per income group surpassed an average maximum rate of 0.5% of the population per day: 7% of HICs, 2% of UMICs, and 5% of LLMICs.

Figure 7.4: Vaccine administration in Mexico. The blue line shows the average rate over the whole vaccination campaign. The yellow line shows the average rate when administration was rate limiting.
In LMICs and LICs, there was arguably not a period of vaccine delivery in which the rate was limited by neither demand nor supply. Therefore we use an alternative source to validate our choices of administration rate in different scenarios.
Figure 7.5 shows that in 40% of vaccination campaigns in LLMICs, the rate exceeded 0.2% of the population per day; in 28% of campaigns, the rate exceeded 0.4% of the population per day; and in 13% of campaigns, the rate exceeded 1% of the population per day. We use these rates of delivery for LLMIC synthetic countries.
![Vaccine administration rates in LLMICs. Shown is the cumulative distribution of delivery rate, measured as the % of the population vaccinated per day. The data consist of 141 points, from 55 countries that are currently classified as LIC or LMIC, from the years 2000 to 2022, of programmes for measles, MR or MMR vaccines, lasting two weeks or more [@whoSummaryMeaslesRubellaSupplementary2022]. The types of programme include campaigns and outbreak response as well as catch up, follow up, speed up, and mop up.](/robj411/p2_drivers/raw/main/README_files/figure-gfm/vaccinationrates.png)
Figure 7.5: Vaccine administration rates in LLMICs. Shown is the cumulative distribution of delivery rate, measured as the % of the population vaccinated per day. The data consist of 141 points, from 55 countries that are currently classified as LIC or LMIC, from the years 2000 to 2022, of programmes for measles, MR or MMR vaccines, lasting two weeks or more (WHO 2022). The types of programme include campaigns and outbreak response as well as catch up, follow up, speed up, and mop up.
We use a broad Beta distribution with parameters (5,5) to describe the compliance of the population with the requirement to isolate if symptomatic or positive. A YouGov survey (Jones, Sarah P, Imperial College London Big Data Analytical Unit, and YouGov Plc 2020) asked “If you were advised to do so by a healthcare professional or public health authority to what extent are you willing or not to self-isolate for 7 days?” The question was asked in 30 different countries (21 high income, five upper-middle income, four lower-middle income) and 63 different weeks of the COVID-19 pandemic to a total of 837,368 people.
The possible answers were ‘Very unwilling’, ‘Somewhat unwilling’, ‘Neither willing nor unwilling’, ‘Not sure’, ‘Somewhat willing’, ‘Very willing’. Excluding the answer ‘Not sure’, and weighting all other answers on a uniform scale of 0 to 1, the average compliance from all participants is 84%. The range across countries is 73% to 90%. The average value for the UK is 87%. In contrast, Smith et al. (2021) found that duration-adjusted adherence to full self isolation was 42.5%. The average value for Australia was 88%. A survey undertaken in 2009 found that 55% of households complied with quarantine requirements (https://doi.org/10.1186/1471-2334-11-2).
In general in this notation, subscripts are indices, and superscripts
are never indices but instead define new labels. In particular, note
that numerical superscripts are attached to letters
Letter | Script | Subscript | Superscript |
---|---|---|---|
consumption | community (contacts) | ||
COMPARTMENT: Died | related to death state | ||
COMPARTMENT: Exposed | related to exposed state | ||
GDP | |||
COMPARTMENT: Hospitalised | related to hospitalised state | ||
hospital capacity | |||
Infectious | |||
COMPARTMENT: Infectious asymptomatic | related to asymptomatic state | ||
COMPARTMENT: Infectious symptomatic | related to symptomatic state | ||
MAX: strata | |||
Loss (cost calculation) | |||
number of people by sector (workforce in place) | |||
CONTACTS: community | |||
CONTACTS: community, home | |||
CONTACTS: community, customers | |||
CONTACTS: community, public transport | |||
CONTACTS: community, school | |||
CONTACTS: work, worker to customer | |||
CONTACTS: work, customer to worker | |||
CONTACTS: total | |||
Total contacts by five-year age bands | |||
Total contacts by DAEDALUS age groups | |||
number of people by stratum | |||
Number of people by five-year age bands | |||
Number of people in DAEDALUS age groups | |||
– | |||
(probability) | |||
COMPARTMENT: Recovered | related to recovered state | ||
Basic reproduction number | |||
Effective reproduction number | |||
COMPARTMENT: Susceptible | MAX: sectors | ||
COMPARTMENT: Susceptible seroconverting | |||
duration from vaccination to protection | |||
duration in hospital | |||
duration in hospital given death | |||
duration in hospital given recovery | |||
duration asymptomatic | |||
duration symptomatic | |||
duration symptomatic given hospitalised | |||
duration symptomatic given recovery | |||
latent period | |||
MAX: vaccines | |||
worker (contacts) | |||
GDP | MAX: years | ||
max GDP | |||
Capital letters
Letter | Script | Subscript | Superscript |
---|---|---|---|
INDEX: age index, five-year age bands | asymptomatic | ||
proportion of tourism that is international | |||
fraction international tourism reduces to as a consequence of the pandemic | seroconverting | ||
deaths per million | |||
government mandate | |||
education sector (j index) | |||
functions: UTR, hospitalisation | |||
INDEX: age index, DAEDALUS age groups | |||
INDEX: dummy index | |||
self isolating | |||
INDEX: stratum index | |||
state transition rates | |||
life expectancy | |||
number of strata | |||
number of sectors | |||
number of vaccines | |||
number of years in work | |||
– | |||
parameters | |||
proportions working from home | |||
discount rate | |||
symptomatic | |||
student strata (j index) | |||
time (day) | |||
dummy variable | INDEX: dummy index | ||
INDEX: vaccination status | |||
sector openness | |||
GVA | INDEX: year | ||
fraction of GDP coming from the Food and accommodation sector |
Lower-case letters
Letter | Definition |
---|---|
transmission rate | |
ratio transmission from asymptomatic | |
vaccine effects | |
growth rate | |
– | |
transmission modifier | |
max time | |
– | |
Greek letters
Letter | Definition |
---|---|
rate of infection | |
rate of onset of asymptomatic infection | |
rate of recovery from asymptomatic infection | |
rate of onset of symptomatic infection | |
rate of recovery from symptomatic infection | |
rate of hospitalisation | |
rate of recovery from hospitalisation | |
rate of death from hospitalisation | |
rate of vaccine seroconversion | |
vaccination rate | |
rate of infection | |
rate of infection |
Rates
Letter | Definition |
---|---|
probability to be symptomatic | |
Basic probability to be hospitalised | |
Adjusted probability to be hospitalised | |
Basic probability to die | |
Adjusted probability to die | |
Compliance with the instruction to self isolate | |
fraction of cases identified by testing | |
proportion of asymptomatic infectiousness averted due to self isolating | |
proportion of symptomatic infectiousness averted due to self isolating | |
tourism parameter | |
tourism parameter | |
tourism parameter | |
minimum mobility | |
deaths coefficient for mobility | |
mandate coefficient for mobility | |
mobility mixing parameter | |
present value of lost earnings | |
mean annual earnings | |
effective amount of education lost per student | |
rate of return for one year of education | |
relative effectiveness of remote education | |
number of days from onset of infectiousness to self isolation | |
number of asymptomatic days spent in self isolation per day of infectiousness | |
number of symptomatic days spent in self isolation per day of infectiousness | |
number of days from onset of symptoms to self isolation | |
public transport mode share | |
work absence, asymptomatic (cost calculation) | |
work absence, symptomatic (cost calculation) | |
school absence, asymptomatic (cost calculation) | |
school absence, symptomatic (cost calculation) | |
fraction of symptomatic infectiousness that is presymptomatic | |
hospitality openness |
Parameters
Ananthapavan, Jaithri, Marj Moodie, Andrew J. Milat, and Rob Carter. 2021. “Systematic Review to Update ‘Value of a Statistical Life’ Estimates for Australia.” International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 18 (11). https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18116168.
Béraud, Guillaume, Sabine Kazmercziak, Philippe Beutels, Daniel Levy-Bruhl, Xavier Lenne, Nathalie Mielcarek, Yazdan Yazdanpanah, Pierre Yves Boëlle, Niel Hens, and Benoit Dervaux. 2015. “The French Connection: The First Large Population-Based Contact Survey in France Relevant for the Spread of Infectious Diseases.” PLoS ONE 10 (7): 1–22. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0133203.
Betthäuser, Bastian A, Anders M Bach-Mortensen, and Per Engzell. 2023. “A Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis of the Evidence on Learning During the COVID-19 Pandemic.” Nature Human Behaviour 7 (March). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-022-01506-4.
Cutler, David M., and Lawrence H. Summers. 2020. “The COVID-19 Pandemic and the $16 Trillion Virus.” JAMA 324 (15). https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20170046.
Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar, and Marcel P. Timmer. 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.” American Economic Review 105 (10): 3150–82.
Global Burden of Disease Collaborative Network. 2021. “Global Burden of Disease Study 2019 (GBD 2019) Reference Life Table.” Seattle, United States of America: Institute for Health Metrics and Evaluation (IHME).
Gottlieb, Charles, Jan Grobovšek, Markus Poschke, and Fernando Saltiel. 2021. “Working from Home in Developing Countries.” European Economic Review 133: 103679. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2021.103679.
Hammitt, James K. 2020. “Valuing Mortality Risk in the Time of COVID-19.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 61 (2): 129–54. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-020-09338-1.
Haw, David, Giovanni Forchini, Patrick Doohan, Paula Christen, Matteo Pianella, Rob Johnson, Sumali Bajaj, et al. 2022. “Optimizing Social and Economic Activity While Containing SARS-CoV-2 Transmission Using DAEDALUS.” Nature Computational Science 2: 223–33. https://doi.org/10.25561/83928.
Jarvis, Christopher I, Pietro Coletti, Jantien A Backer, James D Munday, Christel Faes, Philippe Beutels, Christian L. Althaus, et al. 2023. “Social Contact Patterns Following the COVID-19 Pandemic: A Snapshot of Post-Pandemic Behaviour from the CoMix Study.” MedRxiv.
Jones, Sarah P, Imperial College London Big Data Analytical Unit, and YouGov Plc. 2020. “Imperial College London YouGov Covid 19 Behaviour Tracker Data Hub.”
Moscoviz, Laura, and David K Evans. 2022. “Learning Loss and Student Dropouts During the COVID-19 Pandemic: A Review of the Evidence Two Years After Schools Shut Down.” Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.
Patrinos, Harry Anthony. 2023. “The Longer Students Were Out of School, the Less They Learned.” Journal of School Choice 17 (2): 161–75. https://doi.org/10.1080/15582159.2023.2210941.
Prem, Kiesha, Kevin van Zandvoort, Petra Klepac, Rosalind M. Eggo, Nicholas G. Davies, Alex R. Cook, and Mark Jit. 2021. “Projecting Contact Matrices in 177 Geographical Regions: An Update and Comparison with Empirical Data for the COVID-19 Era.” PLoS Computational Biology 17 (7). https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pcbi.1009098.
Psacharopoulos, George, Victoria Collis, Harry Anthony Patrinos, and Emiliana Vegas. 2021. “The COVID-19 Cost of School Closures in Earnings and Income Across the World.” Comparative Education Review 65 (2).
Robinson, Lisa A., Ryan Sullivan, and Jason F. Shogren. 2021. “Do the Benefits of COVID-19 Policies Exceed the Costs? Exploring Uncertainties in the Age–VSL Relationship.” Risk Analysis 41 (5): 761–70. https://doi.org/10.1111/risa.13561.
Smith, Louise E., Henry W. W. Potts, Richard Amlôt, Nicola T. Fear, Susan Michie, and G. James Rubin. 2021. “Adherence to the Test, Trace, and Isolate System in the UK: Results from 37 Nationally Representative Surveys.” The BMJ 372. https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.n608.
The Global Fund. 2022. “Fight for What Counts Investment Case,” 1–4.
UN Economic and Social Affairs. 2008. International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities Revision 4. New York: United Nations. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781781955659.00009.
UN Tourism. 2023a. “International Tourism and COVID-19.”
———. 2023b. “Key Tourism Statistics.”
Walker, Patrick G. T., Charles Whittaker, Oliver J. Watson, Marc Baguelin, Peter Winskill, Arran Hamlet, Bimandra A. Djafaara, et al. 2020. “The Impact of COVID-19 and Strategies for Mitigation and Suppression in Low- and Middle-Income Countries.” Science 369 (6502): 413–22. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.abc0035.
Whittaker, Charles, Gregory Barnsley, Daniela Olivera Mesa, Daniel J Laydon, Chee Wah Tan, Feng Zhu, Rob Johnson, et al. 2024. “Quantifying the Impact of a Broadly Protective Sarbecovirus Vaccine in a Future SARS-X Pandemic.” https://doi.org/10.1101/2024.08.12.24311730.
WHO. 2022. “Summary of Measles-Rubella Supplementary Immunization Activities.”